Measuring Industrial Policy

A Text Based Approach

Since the 18th century, policymakers have debated the merits of industrial policy (IP). Yet, economists lack basic facts about its use due to measurement challenges. We propose a new approach to IP measurement based on information contained in policy text. We show how off-the-shelf supervised machine learning tools can be used to categorize industrial policies at scale. Using this approach, we validate longstanding concerns with earlier approaches to measurement which conflate IP with other types of policy. We apply our methodology to a global database of commercial policy descriptions, and provide a first look at IP use at the country, industry, and year levels (2010-2022). The new data on IP suggest that i) IP is on the rise; ii) modern IP tends to use subsidies and export promotion measures as opposed to tariffs; iii) rich countries heavily dominate IP use; iv) IP tends to target sectors with an established comparative advantage, particularly in high-income countries.

Figure 1. Model Classification of Policies with Identifiable Goals

(a) All Industrial Policies

(b) National Policies

Industrial policy has been at the center of policy debates since the 18th century. Yet one of the biggest challenges in studying it has been measurement. The same policy instrument (for example, a tariff) can serve very different purposes. It might be used to support a domestic industry, but also to raise revenue, or respond to a crisis.

In our research we develop a text-based approach to industrial policy. We train and validate a Large Language Model (LLM), more specifically, BERT, to identify industrial policies by analyzing the text from the interventions in the Global Trade Alert (GTA) database (Evenett, 2019).

We start or workflow by defining industrial policy as deliberate government action aimed at altering the composition of the domestic economy to achieve a public goal. Then we manually label ~6% of our dataset (2,932 observations) into 3 categories: “Industrial Policy”, “Other Intention” and “Not enough Information”. Third, we train and validate our BERT model to identify industrial policy, achieving 95% accuracy. Lastly, we deploy our best model to classify 47,283 policies in the period between 2010-2022.

We present here the key takeaways from our working paper, along with the data behind each figure.

You can read the full Working Paper here, and access our main dataset here.

Acknowledgments: We gratefully acknowledge the use of the Global Trade Alert (GTA) dataset, kindly shared with us by the GTA team. We are particularly thankful to Johannes Fritz for helpful discussions about the GTA project.

Note on Figure 1: Juhász et al. (2025). Policy classification from BERT model. This exercise excludes policies with no identifiable policy goal (labeled as “Not Enough Information”). Panel (a) shows simple aggregate counts from all the policies in our sample. Panel (b) excludes firm-specific policies.

Fact 1 - Industrial policy is important and on the rise

Throughout our analysis we present: i) simple total counts of industrial policy activity; ii) national policy counts (excluding policies implemented at the firm level); and iii) counts of the implementing public entity using data on the institutions deploying industrial policies, from Juhász and Lane (2004) and Field (2024). The baseline measure (i) might be difficult to compare across countries if policies are reported at different levels of granularity. The second (ii) and third (iii) measures address these issues.

Our first result is that Industrial Policy is important. Figure 1 shows the results of the classification from our BERT model. As seen in the figure, 44-62% of the policies with identifiable goals in our dataset are industrial policy.

Our results also indicate that Industrial policy is on the rise. Figure 2 presents a time trend for industrial policy. We use the value in 2010 as a baseline (indexed to 100). Panel (a) shows that the count of all industrial policies implemented between 2010 and 2022 has increased more than thirtyfold. In panel (b), we focus on National-level industrial policy activity. We exclude policies aimed at specific firms. Here we can see that Industrial Policy activity increased fifteenfold. These results indicate that the GTA is not merely capturing policies at a more granular level over time.

Lastly, in panel (c), we count unique implementing agencies each year. As we can see, in 2022, the number of public agencies announcing at least one new industrial policy worldwide was nearly an order of magnitude higher than in 2010.

Note on Figure 2: Juhász et al. (2025). This figure shows the time-trend of industrial policy between 2010-2022. We follow GTA guidance and use only policies recorded by the GTA in the same year that they were announced for this exercise. The figure is presented as an index with the year 2010 set as the base year (indexed to 100). Panel (a) shows all industrial policies, panel (b) shows excludes policies directed at specific firms, panel (c) shows the entities implementing industrial policy.

Figure 2. Time Trend of Industrial Policy Activity

(a) All Industrial Policies

(b) National Policies

(c) Distinct Entities Implementing Industrial Policies

Fact 2 - Contemporary industrial policy typically uses export-related measures and subsidies and rarely import tariffs.

Figure 3. The Instruments of Industrial Policy

(a) All Industrial Policies

(b) National Policies

(c) Entity-Policy Instrument Pairs

Our second finding is that contemporary Industrial Policy is deployed typically using subsidies and export-related measures. Figure 3 shows the aggregate counts of the interventions we classify as industrial policy disaggregated by UNCTAD’s MAST Group. As seen in the figure, subsidies and export-related measures (e.g., trade financing) account for the bulk of contemporary industrial policy activity.

Notably, IP activity deployed via subsidies and export-related measures is close to an order of magnitude more common than import tariffs, even based on our most conservative estimates. Specifically, panel (b) (national policies) and (c) (implementing agency) cover the concern that our count-based measure of IP activity may overstate the importance of measures such as subsidies relative to tariffs, as the former may be reported at the more granular, firm level of implementation.

Our findings contrast long-held assertions regarding industrial policy. First, tariffs give an incomplete picture of industrial policy, since most of the tariff measures do not seem to be used for IP goals. Second, while in earlier period tariffs may have been more commonly used for IP goals, contemporary industrial policy is not protectionist. To the contrary, much industrial policy seems designed to facilitate participation in export markets. Finally, our findings highlight that modern industrial policy requires fiscal resources and high administrative capacity. States need sufficient fiscal revenue to subsidize firms and promote exports. These dimensions of state capacity provide crucial context for interpreting our next stylized fact.

Note on Figure 3: Juhász et al. (2025). The charts show the top eight most used policy instruments by all the measures. We do not include more because the amount of IP activity is so small as to be hardly visible. The top eight most-used policy instruments by each measure of IP activity are the same, and the excluded policy instruments are the same for each measure of IP activity, too. The excluded MAST chapter codes are: Price-control measures, Migration measures, Capital control measures, Finance measures, Intellectual property, Contingent trade-protective measures.

Fact 3 - Industrial policy is heavily used by high-income economies

Figure 4. Industrial Policy Activity by Income Level

Our third finding is that, there is a strong positive correlation between industrial policy activity, and income levels. Figure 4 plots the distribution of industrial policy by income quintile. Our results show that that countries in the top income quintile deploy five to fifteen times as many industrial policies as countries in the lowest income quintile.

Note on Figure 4: Juhász et al. (2025). We split all countries in our data into income quintiles based on 2010 GDP per capita (Constant 2015 USD) data from the World Bank. Higher quintile means higher income. We present simple aggregate sum of all the policies classified as industrial policies by our BERT model.

Figure 5. Regressions of Industrial Policy Activity on Income Quintiles

(a) All Industrial Policies

(b) National Policies

(c) Entities Implementing Industrial Policies

We formally examine the relationship between industrial policy activity and income by running a regression of a country's (log) total number of industrial policies on a set of binary indicator variables that denote the income quintile of each country in our dataset.

Figure 5 plots the resulting coefficients for each income quintile. This formal test shows that higher income quintiles are associated with greater use of industrial policy. Our coefficient of interest is large, and the difference is statistically significant for the fourth and fifth income quintiles— representing high-income countries. The baselines estimates (with no controls) suggest that total IP activity in the fourth and fifth income quintile is 500-2000% greater than in the poorest income quintile.

Our results are robust to controlling for: the size of the country, the count of exported products (to approximate the diversification of the economy), and the total number of observed policies (though the point estimates shrink in magnitude).

The regression results suggest that different reporting standards are unlikely to account for the patterns, as they hold across all three different measures of IP activity (Panels a-c).

Note on Figure 5: Juhász et al. (2025). We regress the log of measures of IP activity on income quintiles with the first quintile being the excluded category. We split all countries in our data into income quintiles based on 2010 GDP per capita data from the World Bank. Data on 2010 population comes from the World Bank. Data on the number of HS6 sector codes traded by each country comes from COMTRADE.

Fact 4 - Industrial policy is correlated with revealed comparative advantage in high-income economies

Our fourth fact examines the types of industries targeted by new industrial policy activity. We explore this by studying the relationship between our measures of industrial policy and the country’s revealed comparative advantage (RCA) by sector. Our findings suggest that sectors with higher RCA are more likely to receive new industrial policy interventions.

We also study targeting heterogeneity depending on income levels. We regress a binary indicator of industrial policy activity, in a given sector, year and country, on a given country’s quintile distribution of RCA. Figure 6 shows the results of these estimations. For high-income countries (Panel a), we see a strongly increasing monotonic relationship between a sector's position in the RCA distribution and the probability of receiving a new industrial policy. Panels (b) and (c) show there is no similar effect for low- and middle-income countries. Therefore, our results indicate that industrial policy is correlated with revealed comparative advantage in high-income economies.

Note on Figure 6: Juhász et al. (2025). We regress an indicator of industrial policy that takes value of one if HS (2-digit) sector k, country c, and year t, has at least one new industrial policy announcement. The independent variable takes the value of one if RCA is in quintile i, of country c's distribution of Revealed Comparative Advantage in year t. All regressions include country-year fixed effects and cluster standard errors by country. The ommitted category is the lowest quintile of the RCA distribution. Income data uses World Bank GDP per capita in 2010 (USD constant 2015). High income refers to quintiles 4 and 5. Middle income refers to quintile 3. Low-income refers to quintiles 1 and 2.

Figure 6. Regression of Sectoral Industrial Policy Activity by Income Levels and Revealed Comparative Advantage

(a) High-Income Countries

(b) Middle-Income Countries

(c) Low-Income Countries

REFERENCES

Evenett, Simon J, “Protectionism, State Discrimination, and International Business since the On set of the Global Financial Crisis,”Journal of International Business Policy, 2019, 2(1), 9–36.

Juhász, Réka and Lane, Nathaniel and Oehlsen, Emily and Pérez, Verónica C., Measuring Industrial Policy: A Text-Based Approach (May 20, 2025). Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=5262841 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.5262841